We Need Another Model for Development

Ashok Khosla


Over the past fifty years, the world as a whole has made undeniable, and often quite dramatic, "progress" on many fronts. People in scores of countries have attained unprecedented levels of health, wealth and knowledge. Diseases that were for millennia the scourges of whole nations have been conquered. Food production has grown to levels unimagined even a few decades ago. An ever growing range of products from industry is accessible to an ever growing range of customers. And cheap sources of energy have made possible facilities for travel and communication that enable large numbers of people to acquire knowledge and live a life of convenience and comfort on a scale never known before.

However, the flip side of this development coin presents a very different tale. The forests, rivers and soils of large parts of the world have experienced greater and more rapid deterioration in the past few decades than they had over the preceding thousands of years. Species are becoming extinct at a rate that is rapidly approaching levels comparable to those of the mass extinction that wiped out the dinosaurs. Climate change caused by human activity is now one of the top items on the international agenda. These pressures on the Earth’s natural resources have been extensively documented in The Environmental Data Reports of the UN Environment Programme and by other international agencies.

The negative impacts of "development" are not confined to environmental issues alone. There is perhaps more alienation today – with the accompanying proliferation of drugs, crime and violence, often manifested as acts of terrorism and ethnic aggression which are the daily subjects of newspaper headlines all over the world. More pervasive – though possibly less visible – is the deprivation left behind by the process of development: poverty, hunger, vulnerability, indebtedness and rapid population growth. UNDP’s annual Human Development Report presents data showing the decline of social capital, particularly in developing countries, and the alarming growth in economic disparities throughout the world.

Much of the "progress" we have made has, thus, been achieved at the expense of natural and social capital which have diminished precipitously as a result. Unprecedented creation of wealth has gone hand in hand with unprecedented expansion of poverty.

International recognition of the gravity of these issues was first expressed in the convening of the United Nations Conference on the Human Environment at Stockholm in 1972, which engendered a two decade long series of world conferences on environmental and social issues culminating in the Earth Summit at Rio de Janeiro in 1992. The decade since the Earth Summit has continued to witness a growing international debate on these and related issues, including the Millennium Summit in New York in 2000 and the World Summit on Sustainable Development at Johannesburg.

The Context of Development Planning and Implementation

Experiences with planning and implementation of development programmes differ, of course, from country to country. There have certainly been projects over the years that can be counted, by any standards, as success stories. However, there are many others that cannot, and it is important that the international community derive whatever lessons it can to enable it to design more effective strategies for the future.

A few generalizations are possible regarding some of the basic attributes of development programmes as practised through much of the developing world. There exists a broad consensus, based on analysis of numerous development projects, that a large part of past development activity can be characterized as being:

By and through Governments: In most developing countries, the responsibility for planning and executing action for national development rests almost entirely with governments, public sector organisations and external agencies employed by the government. This often leads to inappropriate design of development action and assignment of inappropriate roles, government taking responsibility for activities better done by others.

Top down: This means that decisions are often made and legitimized without adequate participation of the people affected by them.

Narrowly Sectoral: Designed as projects (see below), most development activity ends up by having a narrow, short-term focus, often in conflict with the requirements of sustainable development.

Inflexible: Organised and executed by bureaucratic systems that are heavily constrained by poor professional motivation, fear of innovation, aversion to risk, the tyranny of rigid budget lines and the artificial deadlines of financial year-ends, it becomes difficult to introduce much imagination into development projects.

Externally driven: Because of both the inadequate availability of local expertise, and the plentiful availability of external funding, many governments have relied heavily on expatriate consultants to formulate their economic development plans.

Moreover, such development activities almost never leave behind:

Local ownership of assets: If the local "beneficiaries" have not contributed to the design or implementation of development action, it is only understandable that they are often alienated from the results – which they sometimes proceed to undermine or not use.

Capacity for the future: When there is little involvement of local people or sense of ownership among them, there is little possibility for building up local capacity to innovate, incubate or multiply solutions for their remaining needs.

The Project Mode of Implementation

No matter what the conceptual basis of development policy is at any time, most development action, particularly that funded by overseas sources, is implemented in the form of projects. This, in itself is not always or necessarily undesirable. The project is an excellent, logical framework for achieving stated goals. A well designed project clearly defines the outputs expected and the inputs, in terms of money, resources and time, needed. Before starting, or even before a decision is made to undertake the project, the outputs and inputs can be appraised to determine the worthwhileness of the project. During implementation, the project documentation helps different actors dovetail their contributions efficiently and effectively. Well executed projects can provide for a high level of transparency and accountability, both essential in any development activity.

Despite the demonstrated value of the project as a means of working towards development goals, however, and the long-standing reliance of most development agencies on it, one must also recognize the limitations of this approach. Some of these limitations can, unfortunately, pose severe barriers to the attainment of goals critical to making development sustainable. Whether these limitations are general — inherent and integral to the project as a device for implementation — or are specific to a project – for example, simply the result of poor project formulation — they are so pervasive that one must accept them as inseparable from the very idea of a project.

Although the project mode of implementation is amenable to participatory decision making, it is often carried out by governments and businesses in a way that is seen to be autocratic and arrogant. This can reduce the value of both its outcome and its impacts significantly.

Even with the sophisticated quantitative techniques evolved by welfare economists to include an ever wider array of benefits and costs in the appraisal of projects, actual calculations are subject to a wide range of interpretations. At the heart of the calculations lies the discount rate, which is supposed to reflect the time preference of consumers and producers for the benefits they receive from the project. Given the nature of the exponential function used in such calculations, it turns out that no realistic discount rate can at the same time reflect the imperatives of sustainability. Any discount rate that could be chosen is either too low for the consumer or too high for nature. This means in practice that benefit-cost analysis almost always overvalues the immediate economic benefits of a project and undervalues the environmental, social and other costs, particularly in the long run.

With all their advantages, for certain purposes projects suffer from severe limitations. As mentioned above, their reliance on centrally conceived, highly focused, narrowly designed processes can help achieve results – but not always of the kind needed. For sustainable development, longer time horizons and more intangible side benefits are needed than can usually be addressed by projects.

Limits of Current Development Strategies

Although not everyone would necessarily agree with each detail, there appears to be a widespread perception that the outcomes of current development strategies are not commensurate with the inputs that have gone into them. Among the shortfalls, the most commonly mentioned are:

Implementation gap: Even when development projects achieve their output targets, a large proportion never achieve the full impacts they were designed for.

Accountability gap: The mechanisms for holding project authorities responsible for achieving their goals are weak, primarily because the local stakeholders are not adequately involved or do not have the requisite watchdog skills.

Continuity gap: Development projects intended to have long term continuity often wind down or close up once the project funding comes to an end.

Replicability/scalability gap: Development programmes that serve as exemplary models which are adopted by others for replication and scaling up are not as common as should be expected, given the quality of resources that go into their planning and implementation.

Multiplier gap: Real economic transformation occurs when development activity leads to leveraging positive impacts outside its own domain – and yields positive side benefits which produce multipliers that can resonate through the economy. Projects in the past have often led, on the contrary, to negative impacts on the environment and to disruptions in traditional practices that previously were at least viable.

Sustainability gap: Most development projects are based primarily on economic criteria and often have negative, unintended consequences on social and environmental issues which could have been avoided or minimized through proper consultation with the stakeholders. In any case, despite extensive development effort, inequity and injustice, marginalization and social exclusion continue to remain at unacceptably high levels and the quality of the environmental resource base is heading toward unacceptably low ones.

In addition to these, there are some opportunities, crucial to building the capacity of a society to design its own future, often missed by international development initiatives, leading to missing links in society such as:

Technology gap: Development programmes, particularly those that are largely driven by external consideration often lead to inappropriate technology choices and considerable waste of capital resources. Often their biggest failure is to leave behind little or no "technicity", or the ability to master technology and appropriate it for use suited to local needs and resources.

Institutional gap: Although development programmes have occasionally led to the establishment of effective institutions for innovation, incubation and delivery of solutions, the achievements over the past fifty years falls far short of what is needed.

Leadership gap: Perhaps the greatest failure of international development is its poor record in build local leaders who can help their societies make informed decisions and design development strategies more in tune with their own aspirations and resource endowments. Rather, in many places it appears to have contributed to an acceleration of the opposite process, the brain drain.

Need for Evolving Better Development Approaches – Building Capacity

Given the significant gaps described above between the expectations from 50 years of international development practice, and the actual outcomes, it was only natural that by the early 1990s there would be a growing demand for new approaches to development. This demand grew in urgency as the imperatives of competing in a rapidly globalizing economy became apparent in even the poorest countries. And, with worldwide communications beginning to bring new messages to every home, creating rising expectations for such values as better quality of life, participation and environmental management, this demand became increasingly widespread and pressing. By the time of the Earth Summit at Rio de Janeiro, there was a broad-based concern among both donors and recipients that international development strategies needed to be redesigned.

Out of the Rio process came an understanding that, in addition to redesigning conventional, project based development activities to close the gaps identified above and make them more sustainable, much more emphasis is needed on a particular new form of development cooperation: the building of local capacity.

Simply defined, "Capacity" is people who have the ability, backed by the decision systems and infrastructure they need, to identify, formulate and analyse the problems of high relevance to their societies and design effective strategies to solve them. To be effective, such capacity needs to be built up in all sectors of society – government, business, academia, media, civil society – with opportunities for strong collaborative experiences leading to a tradition of dynamic interaction among them. To play its fullest role, capacity in this sense has to be built up at all levels of society: the national, provincial and local. It is only when a local community acquires capacity to design and create its own future that genuine development can take place. Basically, capacity is synonymous with leadership, informed leadership in all walks of life.

A country or a community with the requisite capacity should be able to choose among different technology options and adopt those most appropriate for local markets and conditions. Capacity also enables societies to implement solutions and learn lessons from experience so as to redesign future solutions even more effectively. Above all, capacity is needed in each country to recognize issues of self-interest, advocate more sustainable policies and negotiate effectively in bringing these about.

In time, capacity grows with the building of institutions and infrastructure and is reinforced by infrastructure of all types – social, physical, financial and communication. Such local institutions must be able to integrate economic, social and environmental issues into the development process at the national, provincial and local levels.

These local institutions and experts will need to be able to design strategies with longer time horizons that lead to development multipliers by creating public awareness and potential for meaningful participation in decision making. This means strengthening their ability to deal with increasingly complex, "harder" issues such as those concerned with technology, innovation, structures of governance, economic and trade issues and to design new development strategies that are more appropriate to local needs. It also means encouraging national counterparts to confront vested interests, attack business-as-usual mindsets and evolve strategic alliances with others working towards the same overall goals, not always easy tasks for an international agency to undertake.

At the national and local level, countries need to create a new cadre of people with a sense of national purpose, a sense of excellence and a sense of commitment. In order to achieve this, they must evolve better understanding of the inter-relationships between economic, social and environmental issues such as the poverty – population – marginalisation cycles and the pitfalls and opportunities offered by emerging issues such as global change, CDM, trade and WTO. At the local level, Capacity Building programmes would have to address such issues as empowering the marginalised, particularly women, and the need for participation and building up a sense of ownership among communities.

International Efforts to Build Capacity

Although there had been some earlier effort by a few donors (such as the Ford and Rockefeller Foundations and some bilaterals and multilaterals) to build capacity, especially in the form of institutions for skill building, it was only in the early nineties, around the Earth Summit at Rio, that the international community began to focus on this concept as an important type of development intervention.

With its Capacity 21 Programme, UNDP set out to assist Developing Countries and Countries in Transition achieve their goals of sustainable development. The task assigned to Capacity 21 was, thus, to undertake systemic programmes in selected countries to build the capacity of local institutions to integrate economic, social and environmental issues into the development process at the national, provincial and local levels.

UNDP itself has operated the Small Grants Programme on behalf of the Global Environmental Facility (GEF) for the past ten years. In addition, GEF has the Medium Sized Project fund largely for this purpose. The World Bank and the International Finance Corporation also manage several capacity building Trust Funds on behalf of various bilateral donor agencies, including those of Japan and the Netherlands. Several bilateral agencies, including the SDC (Switzerland), DFID (UK) and JICA (Japan) have significant capacity building funds, many of them operated through host country intermediaries. Sizable capacity building funds are also available from International and National NGOs and from Foundations

Beyond Capacity 21 – A Vision for the Future

The experiences of UNDP’s Capacity 21 and other related initiatives offer many valuable lessons for the future. First, that fundamental change is needed to make development processes sustainable and such change is possible.

Second, there exist effective and powerful development strategies that do not necessarily follow existing approaches. Examples include: greater reliance on local initiatives involving people to people interaction; emphasis on institutions and decision processes rather than on hardware; and the value of alliances among government, public agencies, civil society and other sectors.

Third, there are no short cuts to sustainable development but the process can be speeded up by using the type of process used by Capacity 21, involving a succession of stages from Demonstration to Validation to Institutionalisation to Mulitiplication. q

 

Evolution of Development Theory and Praxis

During the more than five decades of international development cooperation, multilateral and bilateral agencies have spent large amounts of money in the hope of accelerating the expansion of developing country economies. The resources mobilized by the recipient countries themselves for this effort were even larger, often by one or two orders of magnitude. Yet, with a few exceptions, of the countries that had large populations living below the poverty line at the end of the 2nd World War the bulk are still poor today. Worse, many of them now face the double jeopardy of having lost a large part of their natural and social capital as well.

Much of this "development" effort was influenced by theories of societal change formulated within the discipline of neoclassical economics. These theories, which at any given time largely reflected the doctrines prevailing in the Bretton Woods institutions, have evolved through many cycles over this period. Unfortunately, they have rarely been enriched by a larger understanding of societal, cultural and political processes – a shortcoming that has in many cases led to failure, sometimes total failure, in achieving their stated goals.

Evolution of Development Theory

Starting around 1950 and fortified with the theories of underdevelopment, such as those of Rosenstein-Rodan, and of the staged evolution of economies, such as those of Gerschenkron and Rostow, armies of expatriate consultants went forth to help transform the economies of the poorer regions of the world. In the early days, the emphasis of the policies and interventions they advocated was, in the manner suggested by economists such as Harrod and Domar, largely on increasing savings rates and improving the productivity of industrial capital. Other consultants, such as those who followed the theories of Lewis, promoted investments in industry as a means of creating higher incomes among urban elites whose savings could in due course be expected to trickle down to the poor in the other, mostly agricultural, economy. Still others pursued the theories of economists such as Myint, Haberler and Viner, focusing on international trade as the engine of development.

Some (eg, Prebisch, Singer, Baran, Sweezy, and Amin) advocated more government intervention, others (eg, Bauer, Little, Balassa, Krueger and Johnson) strongly urged less. Some advocated highly centralized planning systems, others believed in more or less complete laissez faire. All of them had powerful, if not seemingly flawless arguments to support their theses. All of them put more faith on their mathematically elegant if narrowly conceived theories than on the empirical facts that often refuted these theories. And all of them had numerous, loyal disciples working out in the field.

Welfare economists such as Little, Adelman, Lal, Marglin and others, devised methods to evaluate the time streams of benefits and costs entailed by a proposed development activity. They also evolved rudimentary techniques for quantifying social and environmental variables that could in principle be included in project decision-making. Such benefit-cost analyses, even though they often had to be based on somewhat unrealistic assumptions regarding discount rates and shadow prices, were widely recognized to be better than no analysis at all and became quite fashionable for appraising development projects.

A few economists, including Seers, Chenery, Singer, Sen, Ul-Haq, Streeten, Daly and Henderson, questioned the heavy reliance of development theory on purely growth-related factors. Some of them went further and tried to include issues of equity and social welfare in their decision models. But most of these attempts did not get incorporated into mainstream development practice.

Evolution of Development Praxis

Emerging from long and sometimes painful colonial experiences, the host countries had their own optics of national interest and chose from a wide spectrum of economic and political frameworks that ranged from Marxist and socialist on the left to outright capitalist on the right.

 

Often, to raise financial capital for their development plans, they had to accept the advice of external policy consultants and adopt development models that were at significant variance with their own policies. The results, in a large part of the developing world, were highly confused and quite dysfunctional economic interventions, often lacking in coherence and occasionally leading to mutually counteracting outcomes, stagnant economies and social conflict.

In the course of the next three or four decades, the developing world thus went through a rapid succession of fashions in economic policy. First there was import substitution. When that did not show adequate results, export promotion (mainly of primary commodities and rudimentary industrial goods) took over. And when neither of these worked, the neo-liberals became more dominant with their advocacy of greater emphasis on international trade. Five Year Plans for capital investments were common during this period. Substantively, the precise sequence of emphasis varied from country to country but in many it went from core industries to infrastructure to agriculture to industry to trade. In some it went the other way.

This phase was followed by a shift into strengthening physical infrastructure and financial institutions. And, in parallel to these, there was the constant refrain calling for structural adjustments in monetary and fiscal policies and for privatization of the ownership of productive assets. In many cases, this was followed by imposition (for example, as conditionality for obtaining financing from multilateral institutions) of fiscal measures such as reducing social expenditures to balance national budgets or lowering of tariff barriers to improve the competitiveness of national industries in global trade. More recently, international donors have also expressed increasing concern for issues of "good governance", participative decision-making and greater involvement of civil society in development planning. The role of centralized economic planning gradually withered away, though in many countries the bureaucracies in charge of this function continue to remain in place.

A parallel trend in recent years has been the gradual realization of a need for investing in social capital such as health and primary education. There also appears to be increasing interest in strengthening local economies through the creation of livelihoods and provision of microcredit. However, these trends remain somewhat marginal: the growth of these types of development intervention is, perhaps, limited by the fact that neither government nor big business has any comparative advantage in providing them.

Throughout this period, the main actors in the design and implementation of development programmes were seen to be government and the public sector, gradually over time giving way to the private sector and, more specifically, corporate businesses. Civil society was seen to be a good ally for carrying out surveys, creating awareness and undertaking "social mobilization", but not for much else.

Yet, the economies of most developing countries are not where, by any objective measure, they should be after so many decades of thoughtful effort. Even the World Bank, the champion of cutting edge thinking on development economics admits that these theories and approaches have not worked satisfactorily.

There is, undoubtedly, some truth and possible value in all such theories. But a national economy is a complex system and the world within which it operates is a system of even greater complexity. For most poor countries, development means transforming a highly inefficient, inequitable and imbalanced economy operating at a low level of transactions to one that is growing rapidly, equitably and sustainably. To succeed in bringing about sustainable development, the interventions must match the complexity of the problems they have to deal with. Often, the approaches listed above have not been able to deliver such interventions. q

 

UNEP Sasakawa Environment Prize 2002

Dr. Ashok Khosla — President, Development Alternatives — has won the United Nations Environment Programme Sasakawa Environment Prize for 2002 for his contributions in the field of Environment. The Award will be presented in New York on November 19, 2002.

Back to Contents

 
    Donation Home

Contact Us

About Us